EnglishНа русском

Переглянути у форматі pdf

TRADE LIBERALIZATION: THEORY, PREDICTING THE CONSEQUENCES OF IMPLEMENTATION AND PRACTICAL REALITIES
Mark Hellyer

Назад

DOI: 10.32702/2306-6814.2019.21.63

УДК: 339.9.012.421

Mark Hellyer

TRADE LIBERALIZATION: THEORY, PREDICTING THE CONSEQUENCES OF IMPLEMENTATION AND PRACTICAL REALITIES

Summary

Background. The competitive positions of countries and their companies largely depend on the nature of participation in international economic interaction. It has been proven that countries with high levels of economic development are benefiting from foreign trade through liberalization. However, it remains debatable how much positive expectations identified in trade liberalization theory can be put into practice in economically peripheral countries.
The fundamental scientific basis for studying the correlation of economic openness in the context of the impact on economic growth, including ambiguous and contradictory impact of trade liberalization, have been studied by various scholars. However, since antagonists of trade liberalization theory often do not fully understand all the positive effects of its application, research in this area is relevant.
The goal of this study is to analyze the development and foundations of trade liberalization theory, as well as to compare projections of the effects of trade liberalization between Ukraine and the EU under the terms of the Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area (DCFTA) and the practical realities.
The main results of the research. International trade theory provides explanations for the impact of international trade and the distribution of the gains from trade and particularly trade liberalisation through preferential trade agreements. Classical trade theory supports free trade and advocates against tariffs and restrictions. The assumptions behind the classical trade theory are the following: Completely free trade; no subsidies, tariffs, or commercial restrictions; Frictionless inter-sectoral transfer of labour. However these assumptions do not hold in the real world and gives rise to the debate on the conditions under which free trade provides Gains from Trade.
In the Heckscher-Ohlin model of trade, each nation's comparative advantage is traced to its particular endowments of different factors of production: that is, basic inputs such as land, labour, and capital. Since the costs of these inputs in each country will depend on their availability, differences in factor endowments across countries will create differences in comparative advantage. Each country will tend to export items whose production requires intensive use of the factors with which it is abundantly endowed relative to other nations; conversely, each country will import goods whose production requires intensive use of factors that are relatively scarce. Therefore, countries well endowed with land, like Australia and Canada, and indeed Ukraine, are thus expected to export agricultural products (e.g., wheat and wool), while importing products that require the intensive use of labour (e.g., textiles and footwear).
The article emphasized that Classical theory and Heckscher-Ohlin theory is further developed by the factor price equalization theory, by Paul A. Samuelson. Economic theory of equalization of factors and prices implies that free trade should lead to trends in the equalization of income, capital and labour in different countries.
The example of graphical models illustrates what to expect in an economy that can move from protection to free trade. It has been shown that this will lead to a net increase in welfare. This made it possible to formulate a scientific understanding of why trade theory supports trade liberalization through preferential trade agreements, such as the DCFTA between the EU and Ukraine. The results of this agreement, as shown by the systematization of short— and long-term expectations, should be to increase trade, more effective allocation of resources, equalise wages and stimulate economic growth. According to forecasts, six sectors in Ukraine were expected to generate additional increases in Exports to the EU of over 20% net. However, we stressed that Ukrainian business entities will only gain access to the domestic market if European standards are established and technical regulations are complied with. At the same time, the cost of implementation of EU standards and retrofitting of production should be compensated by the flow of European investment which is going to stimulate restructuring and retrofitting of companies, facilitate new businesses and, as the result, increase the state' revenues.
Our personal research has revealed that with 4 years of data since the effective application of DCFTA provisions on Ukraine's exports to the EU, it shows that Ukraine's exports have not significantly improved under the DCFTA. This runs contrary to both the EU and Ukrainian policy objective of the DCFTA as well as traditional economic theory.
Conclusions. According to the traditional economic theory, trade liberalization brings not only traditional "static gains" from specialization, but also the adoption of new technologies and skills, leading to "dynamic gains" from trade — to higher productivity. But in the case of the practical implementation of the DCFTA on Ukraine's exports to the EU, the opposite consequences were found. It is noted that the results obtained during this study can be used for further research towards optimizing the processes of liberalization and upholding national economic interests in the context of the objective growth of world trade. Our data can also be used to find the real reasons that did not allow the country to benefit from the implementation of the DCFTA, as well as to develop measures to eliminate or minimize the negative effects.

Keywords: trade liberalization; the Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area; economic growth; tariffs; exports; preferential trade agreements.

References

1. Clemens, M.A. and Williamson, J.G. (2001), "A Tariff-growth Paradox? Protection's Impact the World Around 1875-1997", NBER Working Paper, Series, vol.8549, pp.121—132.
2. Dollar, D and Krаay, A., "Is Good for the Poor", [Online], available at: http://ideas.repec.org/p/wbk/wbrwps/2587.html (Accessed: 20 Oct 2019).
3. Dollar, D. (1992), "Outward-oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985", Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 40, pp. 523—544.
4. Edwards, S. (1998), "Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?", Economic Journal, vol. 108, pp. 383—398.
5. Sachs, J. and Warner, A. (1995), "Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration", Broking Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1, 25th Anniversary Issue, pp. 1—118.
6. Choudhri, E.U. and Hakura, D.S. (2000), "International Trade and Productivity Growth: Exploring the Sectoral Effects for Developing Countries", [Online], available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2000/wp0017.pdf (Accessed: 20 Oct 2019).
7. Duhinets, G.V. and Tronko, V.V. (2015), "Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area between Ukraine and EU (DCFTA): realities and prospects", Ekonomichnyj chasopys-XXI [Economic Annals-XXI], vol. 155 (11—12), pp. 10—13.
8. Francois, J.F. and Manchin, M. (2009), "Economic Impact of a Potential Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between the European Union and the Commonwealth of the Independent States", CASE Network Reports, vol. 84, [Online], available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1393697 (Accessed: 20 Oct 2019).
9. Nugent, J.B. (2002), "Trade liberalization: Winners and Losers, Success and Failures", [Online], available at: http://uoit.ca/sas/International%20Trade/TradeWinnersLosers.pdf (Accessed: 20 Oct 2019).
10. Rodrik, D. (2001), "Trading in illusions", Foreign Policy, vol. 123, pp. 54—63.
11. Petrov, R. Van der Loo, G. and Van Elsuwege, P. (2015), "The EU-Ukraine Association Agreement: A New Legal Instrument of Integration Without Membership?", Kyiv-Mohyla Law and Politics Journal, [Online], available at: http://ekmair.ukma.edu.ua/bitstream/handle/123456789/7874/Petrov_The_EU-Ukraine_Association.pdf?sequence=5 (Accessed: 20 Oct 2019).
12. Vosta, M. Musiyenko, S. and Abrham, J. (2016), "Ukraine-EU Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area as Part of Eastern Partnership initiative", Journal of International Studies, Vol. 9, No 3, pp. 21—35.
13. Hoekman, B. (2016), Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Agreements, European University Institute, San Domenico di Fiesole, Italy.
14. Adarov, A. (2016), Trade Effects of DCFTA: Early Results, Challenges and Potential, Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies, Vienna, Austria.
15. Kryvous, V. (2015), "Association Agreement Between Ukraine and EU: Long-Term Opportunities For Cooperation and Risks of Free Trade Area (FTA/DCFTA)", Journal of European Economy, vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 257—267.
16. Adarov, A. and Havlik, P. (2016), Benefits and Costs of DCFTA: Evaluation of the Impact on Georgia, Moldova and Ukraine, The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies, Bertelsmann Stiftung, Vienna, Austria.
17. Deardorff, A. V. (1980), "The general validity of the law of comparative advantage", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 88, No. 5, pp. 941—957.
18. Feenstra, R. C. (2004), The Heckscher-Ohlin Model. Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton University Press, UK.
19. Berden, K. G. Smakman, F. and Wymenga, P. (2007), Trade Sustainability Impact Assessment for the FTA between the EU and Ukraine within the Enhanced Agreement, Rotterdam, The Netherlands.
20. Sidenko, V. (2007), "EU-Ukraine Relations in the Context of a Possible Free Trade Agreement", EU Working Papers, vol. 3, pp. 3—18.
21. Movchan, V. and Giucci, R. (2011), Quantitative Assessment of Ukraine's Regional Integration Options: DCFTA with European Union vs. Customs Union with Russia, Belarus and Kazakhstan. German Advisory Group, Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting, Berlin/Kyiv, Ukraine.
22. Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting (2014), Consequences of the creation of in-depth and Comprehensive Free Trade Area between Ukraine and the EU, Institute for Economic Research and Policy Consulting, Kyiv, Ukraine.
23. Kravchuk, A. and Popovych, Z. (2016), The expected impact of the EU-Ukraine Association Agreement, Transnational Institute, Amsterdam; Rosa Luxembourg Stiftung, Brussels; Center of Social and Labor Research, Kiev, Ukraine.
24. Jakubiak, M. Kolesnichenko, A. Boyarchuk, D. Golodniuk, I. Mykhaylychenko, M. Paczynski, W. Tsarenko, A. and Vavryschuk, V. (2006), Prospects for EU-Ukraine Economic Relations, Center for Social and Economic Research, CASE Reports, vol. 66, Warsaw, Poland.
25. Usenko, O. (2007), "Review of the Impact of the Ukraine-EU Free Trade Agreement on Manufacturing Industries (Mechanical Engineering, Chemical and Light Industry)", The Journal of International Economic Policy, vol. 2, pp. 67—100.
26. Burakovsky, I. Kutsenko, K. Chukhai, H. Kobylyanska, A. Movchan, V. Razdorozhny, Ye. and Sysenko, N. (2010), Costs and Benefits of FTA between Ukraine and the European Union, Institute For Economic Research and Policy Consulting, Kyiv, Ukraine.

Марк Хеллаєр

ЛІБЕРАЛІЗАЦІЯ ТОРГІВЛІ: ТЕОРІЯ, ПРОГНОЗУВАННЯ НАСЛІДКІВ ВПРОВАДЖЕННЯ ТА ПРАКТИЧНІ РЕАЛІЇ

Ключові слова: лібералізація торгівлі; поглиблена та всеохоплююча зона вільної торгівлі; економічне зростання; тарифи; експорт; пільгові торговельні угоди.

№ 21 2019, стор. 63 - 70

Рубрика: Економіка

Дата публікації: 2019-11-23

Кількість переглядів: 855

Відомості про авторів

Mark Hellyer

postgraduate student, Kyiv National University of Trade and EconomicsDirector of CTA Economic & Export Analysts (UK)

Марк Хеллаєр

аспірант, Київський національний торговельно-економічний університетДиректор компанії "СТА" (Великобританія)

ORCID:

0000-0001-5665-4052

Як цитувати статтю

Hellyer, Mark (2019), “Trade liberalization: theory, predicting the consequences of implementation and practical realities”, Investytsiyi: praktyka ta dosvid, vol. 21, pp. 63–70. DOI: 10.32702/2306-6814.2019.21.63

Creative Commons License

Стаття розповсюджується за ліцензією
Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 Міжнародна.